Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Linear programming and capital budgeting, Summaries of Linear Programming

Resolution. For corporate decisions, the resolution of this matter of "hard" capital rationing is so simple that one can only apologize for having.

Typology: Summaries

2021/2022

Uploaded on 09/27/2022

stifler
stifler 🇮🇹

4

(6)

215 documents

1 / 28

Toggle sidebar

This page cannot be seen from the preview

Don't miss anything!

bg1
pf3
pf4
pf5
pf8
pf9
pfa
pfd
pfe
pff
pf12
pf13
pf14
pf15
pf16
pf17
pf18
pf19
pf1a
pf1b
pf1c

Partial preview of the text

Download Linear programming and capital budgeting and more Summaries Linear Programming in PDF only on Docsity!

••;rfJi?l

MAR 121970

DcWlY library

LINEAR PROGRAMMING AND CAPITAL BUDGETING:

COMMENT

Stewart C. (^) Myers March 1970 445-

LINEAR PROGRAMMING AND CAPITAL BUDGETING; COMMENT

Stewart C. Myers

This paper is the latest, and I hope the last chapter, in the contro- versy begun by William H. Baumol and Richard E. Quandt in their criticism (^) [1]

of Weingartner 's work on capital budgeting under capital rationing [5], A

thorough review^ and^ partial^ resolution^ of^ the^ matter^ has^ been offered by Willard T. Carleton in a recent article [2]. My^ purpose here is to try to complete the job.

Background The Weingartner model, reduced to essentials, is as follows; J T Maximize c^ (^) ^ [a.j./(l+k) ]xi j=l t=0 -"^ (1)

Subject to (^) [i a,.xj. M,; (^) t =^ 0, (^) 1, (2) x^ (^) J = (^) 1.

where: k =^ a fixed discount rate, the "cost of capital"; a4(. =^ the from^ net project^ cash flow, possibly negative, obtained j in^ period^ t; x^ =^ the number of units of (^) j constructed; Mj. = the fixed (^) amount of cash available at t.

Weingartner (^) actually makes a distinction between cash outlays and cash returns. scope of (^) thisHowever, paper. the distinction (^) is not necessary within the restricted

"hard" rationing --^ the case Baumol and Quandt were concerned with. The Baumol-Quandt Solution Baxunol and Quandt recast the basic model as follows:^4 T Maximize (^) *£^ (^) ^t^t ^^^ t=

Subject to ~ (^) [^ (^) ^it^j •^ ^t - '> t =^1 2 T (4) W^, (^) Xj > (^) 0.

where; W^. =^ cash withdrawn for owners' consvm^Jtion in period t; U^ =^ marginal utility of consun?)tion in t^ assumed constant.

This solves the problem^ but not in a wholly useful way. First, the objective is a corporate one, and it is not clear that the usual idea of a project's present value retains meaning. Second, and more in^jortant, the idea of maximizing "utility," while perhaps useful to the individual investor, seems both vague and arbitrary for corporate capital budgeting decisions. As Carleton notes, "Precluded from using the company's cost of capital, [Baumol and Quandt] invoke a subjective discounting procedure whose welfare implications for resource allocation are quite suspect."

[ iJ. p. (^) 326, See Carleton's (^) discussion of this point. (^) [2], p. 829. ^Ibid.

Resolution For corporate decisions, the resolution of this matter of "hard" capital rationing is so simple that one can only apologize (^) for having taken so much space to describe the problem. We assume^ a world^ of certainty,^ and^ the absence of market imperfec- tions except for capital rationing. First, consider^ Eq.^ (4), the constraint in the Baumol-Quandt formula- tion. This will always be a strict equality in (^) the optimal solution, since increasing W^ (^) always increases (^) the objective function. Solving for W^^ and substituting in the objective function, Eq, (^) (3), the problem can be rewritten T J Maximize (^) ^ U(-[M^ + (^) ^ (^) ^it^i^ (3a) t=0 (^) J = '

Subject to

J

Jt (^) J t

-j' (^) \ ^ 0.

= M t = 0, 1,

(4a)

The constant term (^) 2. ^tMt can be dropped from the objective function without harm. The differences of Eqs. (^) (3a) and (4a) from (^) (1) and (2) are the inclu- sion of (^) "slack" variables W and the use of marginal utilities, (^) Ut, rather than the discount (^) factors l/(l+k)t. (^) The extra slack variables are

It is also an equality because sources and (^) uses of funds have to be equal. Any "slack" in such an equation can, and should, (^) be interpreted as another investment project — (^) i.e., investment in cash (^) or liquid assets.

  1. Since^ the^ problem^ does^ not exist, Baumol and Quandt's "solution" is no^ different^ than the original model, as they would have dis- covered had they pushed their analysis a bit (^) further.
  2. The^ existence^ of capital rationing should not change the firm's basic objective. Shareholders' utility is maximized when the firm's current market value (the present value of future dividends) is maximized; and the (^) firm's market value is the sum of the present (^) values of accepted (^) projects.
  3. It is^ not^ true that "if during period t capital is in short

supply and is effectively limited to the amount M , then ...

the firm is thereby necessarily cut off from the capital market and, as a consequence, from any external discounting criteria."^9 The firm always has the option of paying dividends, and the rela- tive values of dividend payments at different points in time is determined by the interest rate k regardless of whether capital is rationed. The "cost of capital" k thus serves perfectly well as an external discounting criterion in the case of "hard" capital rationing.

^Baumol and Quandt (^) [l], (^) p. 322.

APPENDIX

Consider an investor^ in a world of certainty where security prices are determined in the usual way: T R.(t)

P ^ =^ C -J^ (A.l)

t=0 (l+k)*^

where: P (^). (0) =^ price per unit of security (^) j at the beginning of period (^) t =^ 0; R.(0) -" =^ cashhorizon return of j in t, except in the (arbitrary) period T, for which R (^) , (T) =^ any cash pay- ment at T plus P.(T); ^ k =^ the rate of interest, here assumed independent of^ t. The investor's problem is to maximize the utility of his consumption stream over the period t =^ 0, 1, ..., T, subject to the constraint that current wealth, E, be divided between investment and current consumption, C(0). The^ corresponding^ Lagrangian^ expression^ is

V =^ U(C(0),^ C(l)^ C(T))

+ dx (P (0)-R (0)) + CCO)-E)

j J^ J where: x. -" = the number of units of security (^) j purchased; for for t = (^) 1, 2,... (^) , T

C(t) =^ endowed income (assumed given) plus ^ x.R. (t)

.

j "^ -^

Note that x. can be negative— this represents borrowing or selling short.